ABUSE OF DOMINANCE: A Comparative Study with a Focus on the cases against the Big Techs


The concept of abuse of dominant position in the US and EU has some fundamental differences, and it is interesting to note that the competition law in India has seen a shift from more reliance on the EU than the US in dealing with abuse of dominance cases. This is quite evident from the fact that the concept of 'monopolistic trade practices' under the MRTP Act. was nearer to US law of 'monopolization' while the concept of 'abuse of dominance under the Competition Act is nearer to the EU text in Article 102, which prohibits abuse of a dominant position.

While there is a basic distinction in enforcement approach in the EU and US, i.e., there is criminal enforcement of antitrust laws in the US, it is administrative in the EU. India has followed the administrative model in the EU.

Several scholars have lately raised concerns about expanding monopolistic power in the global economy. Concerns have been expressed from across the political spectrum, but the most persistent warnings have come from the self-proclaimed "New Brandeisians," a group of scholars for whom the title of Louis Brandeis's famous essay, "A Curse of Bigness" (Brandeis 1914, chap. 8), has become a mighty rallying cry. Members of this group contend that Google, Amazon, and other large tech companies are engaging in plainly anticompetitive actions to stymie future competitors and get away with it by influencing the political system. They are especially concerned that the existing antitrust doctrine focused on consumer damages has rendered the countries defenseless against bigness' other problems (Lamoreaux, 2019). The New Brandeisians claim that the country has entered a second Gilded Age, and their concerns are similar to those sparked by the emergence of the Standard Oil Trust during that previous era of turbulence. In Standard Oil, the US Supreme Court ordered the dissolution of the Standard Oil Company, which utilized its size and weight in the petroleum sector in several anti-competitive ways. Data has been dubbed the "oil of the twenty-first century."   As a result, it is only reasonable that big techs that mine data and act anti-competitively will face antitrust scrutiny.

Big Tech, sometimes known as the Tech Giants. It refers to the largest, most dominating, and prominent firms in the global information technology sector. As the term 'Big' suggests, each significant technology business is the undisputed leader in its relevant field. Microsoft dominates the Operating Systems industry, Facebook dominates the social media area, Google dominates the search engine business, and Apple dominates communication hardware. These IT companies' notion of dominance has become a significant headache from a competition perspective. Big Tech has a significant influence on the economy and broader society, which raises worries on various fronts, from data privacy to the democratic will forming process. However, the competition problems are exclusively connected to digital markets' proclivity to produce monopolies. Monopolies have negative consequences such as lower output, higher prices, and large expenditures by corporations to establish a monopoly. This also explains the multiple antitrust lawsuits filed against Microsoft, Google, and Facebook.

In this article, I will be analyzing a) A comparative analysis of the US, EU, and India's perspective towards abuse of dominant position. b) Some case studies on the abuse of dominance by Big Techs.


Abuse of Dominance – The Concept

Monopolistic behavior is extensively prohibited by current competition law. The Sherman Act of 1890, which is credited with establishing competition law, has a particular restriction against monopolization. Abuse of dominance (AoD) is prohibited under Article 82 of the EU Treaty. Similarly, section 4 of the Indian Competition Act, 2002 forbids and punishes misuse of a dominant position. It does not frown on domination in general. A company is allowed to expand as much as it wants or gain as large a market share as possible.

The issue only emerges when there is AoD. AoD is one of the most challenging areas of competition law because firms can legitimately achieve dominant positions through innovation, superior production, or more significant entrepreneurial effort. Many practices that appear anti-competitive on the surface can serve legitimate pro-competitive purposes. As a result, in a certain case, various competition authorities may reach different judgments, as seen by the diverse decisions in the Microsoft cases. Experts correctly warn of the "chilling effect" on competition and innovation that might emerge from the incorrect use of AoD laws.

In most AoD instances, three questions arise a) What is the relevant market in which the claimed dominance/abuse occurs? b) Is the company the dominant player in the relevant market? c) What are the particular implicated practices, and are they abusive?

The relevant market comprises two parts: the 'relevant product market' and the 'relevant geographic market .'The 'relevant product market' includes products/services that the customer considers interchangeable or substitutable. Should the product market for soft drinks comprise any or all aerated drinks, fruit drinks, cold coffee, and milk? Is Coca-Cola or Pepsi interchangeable with apple juice?

The 'relevant geographic market' is defined as where competitive conditions are homogenous. For example, in the case of cement, is the regional market to be the entire country or just a small region, such as the Northeast? The Competition Act specifies several variables that the commission must consider when assessing the relevant product and geographic markets.

The second consideration is whether the company is dominant in that relevant market. Again, the act provides a comprehensive list of considerations that the commission should consider for finding dominance, many of which are identical to those evaluated in other countries such as the EU and the UK. The MRTP Act defined dominance only in market share (25 percent or more).

Market share remains an essential consideration under the Competition Act, but other criteria such as entry obstacles, size, resources, economic power and commercial advantages of the company, size, significance of rivals, and so on must also be evaluated.

Thus, if one business has a 45 percent market share while the second firm has a 40 percent market share, the first firm may not be called dominant. However, if the business's stake over other firms is 15% or less, the firm may be considered dominant. However, dominance may be challenging if there are no entry barriers and the business confronts possible competition from new entrants. Entry hurdles might include legislative impediments, significant capital expenditures, a lack of technology, etc.

The final consideration is whether the corporation, assuming genuinely dominant in the relevant market, has exploited its position. The following practices are defined as abuse under the Competition Act, 2002: “unfair or discriminatory prices or conditions, limiting or restricting production or technical or scientific development, denying market access, imposing supplementary contractual obligations unrelated to the subject of the contract, and using dominance in one market to enter/protect another market.”


Abuse of Dominant Position in EU

Article 102 (previously Article 82 EC and prior to that Article 86 EC) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) deals with the provision of abuse of dominant position. Specifically, it lists the types of abuses, in contrast to the US, which relies on judicial interpretation of the concept as noted above. Article 102 of TFEU runs as follows:

"Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position within the internal market or in a substantial part of it shall be prohibited as incompatible with the internal market in so far as it may affect trade between the Member States. Such abuse may, in particular, consist in:

(a) directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions;

(b) limiting production, markets, or technical development to the prejudice of consumers;

(c) applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage;

(d) concluding contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts."

It is essential to highlight that the current Competition Act of India closely matches EU regulations, as evidenced by the provisions themselves as well as the interpretations provided to the legislation by CCI and COMPAT/Supreme Court/High Courts in the previous five years of enforcement. An examination of Article 102 reveals five critical components for proving abuse of dominant position in the EU: “(i) a 'undertaking' – single or collective (ii) a dominating position (iii) held in an internal or common market (iv) abuse and (v) influence on inter-state trade.” Furthermore, in the EU, there are detailed instructions for implementing AOD regulations and determining Relevant Market.


A Dominant Position

The norms of abuse of power apply to 'undertakings.' According to EU rules, this is generally construed and applies to all entities engaged in economic activity, regardless of their legal status or means of financing. As a result, public bodies participating in commercial activity are subject to the abuse of dominance regulations.

According to the EU Guidelines, determining whether an undertaking is in a dominant position and the degree of market power it possesses is the first stage in applying Article 102. While the dominating position is not specified in EU law, it arises from the United Brands Case and is later confirmed in the Hoffman La Roche Case (Radhu & Tare, 2019).

“The dominant position referred to in this Article relates to a position of economic strength enjoyed by undertaking which enables it to prevent effective competition being maintained on the relevant market by giving it the power to behave to and appreciable extent independently of its competitors, customers and ultimately of its consumers.” (Makkar & Jain, 2020)

Another significant difference in the EU approach to dealing with AOD cases is that in the EU, maintaining a dominating position places a special obligation on the undertaking in inquiry, the scope of which must be determined in light of the individual circumstances of each instance. This is not the situation in the United States, where the undertaking bears no unique duty as a result of its dominance.


Types of abuse

 

Exclusionary abuse

Exclusionary abuse is defined as behavior by a dominating business that can prohibit competitors, in whole or in part, from profitably entering or remaining active in a particular market (and which, as an indirect result, will ultimately have a detrimental impact on consumers).

Exclusionary behaviors are often regarded as the most dangerous sort of abuse. This is because they have the potential to weaken the competitive process in the long run by preventing small or new rivals from becoming viable challenges to a dominant business, depriving customers of the opportunity to benefit from more choice and competition. Exclusionary abuse includes (but is not limited to):

Predatory pricing: actions used expressly to eliminate or undermine a competitor's position as a viable competitor (either by forcing it out of the market or by deterring market entry). This is accomplished by a dominating corporation preceding short-term earnings to drive out or dissuade competitors. Once the dominant corporation has effectively rejected current competitors/potential entrants, it has reinforced its position and is allowed to charge supra-competitive rates and/or degrade its services without repercussions.

Refusal to deal: a dominant undertaking's freedom to choose with whom it does business may be limited whereas, as a vertically-integrated undertaking (dominant in an upstream market for the supply/ownership of an important or 'essential' input/facility), it can use its position in the supply of the important or 'essential' input/facility to deny rivals access (thus harming their ability to compete with the dominant undertaking in the downstream market).

Loyalty rebates: a return granted to a client when a certain amount of merchandise is purchased over a specific period—can encourage customers to place all of their purchases with one company rather than splitting their orders among rival companies (effectively amounting to an exclusivity obligation in its effect).

Tying and Bundling: techniques employed by corporations to combine the selling of two unique items together may make competing with the stand-alone products more challenging.

Enforcing patent rights—enforcing one's patent rights by an injunction may constitute an abuse in certain instances.


Exploitative abuses

Unlike exclusionary abuses, which target competitors and so indirectly hurt customers (owing to the exclusion of competitors and a resulting decline in competitive alternatives), 'exploitative abuses' have no negative impact on rivals. Instead, they involve the dominating corporation actively harming consumers (which uses its market power to extract rents from its customers beyond what would typically be achievable).


Reprisal abuses

A 'reprisal' abuse occurs when a dominating firm 'overreacts' to perceived threats to its commercial interests. The dominating corporation seeks to warn, reprimand, or penalize the trade partner/competitor by increasing prices charged, canceling supply or purchase contracts, or initiating legal procedures, among other things. These abuses are frequently exclusionary in their goal and effect, yet the action taken is excessive and unjust (especially regarding trading partners that are not rivals) (constituting an abuse in its own right independent of its exclusionary potential).


The Notion of Abuse of Dominance in the USA

Sherman Act, 1890

The Sherman Act has declared illegal all contracts, combinations or conspiracies prohibiting trade or commerce between states or territories or with foreign countries. The essential requirement is that there must be mutual agreement or commitment to engage in a common course of anticompetitive conduct.

Monopolize and Conspiracy to monopolize

Section 2 of the Sherman Act outlawed (a) Monopolization, (b) attempt to monopolize (c) conspiracies to monopolize.

This section has two basic elements

1) Possession of monopoly power in the relevant market

2) The wilful maintenance of the power.

A person is not guilty until he or she possesses monopolistic power, which is the ability to set pricing and eliminate competitors. As a result, the crime of monopolization necessitates monopolistic power and intent to monopolize; nevertheless, there is no monopoly if the defendant's monopoly power arises as a result of a better product, implying a commercial or historical accident.

Monopolization is covered under the competition act but not a conspiracy to monopolize. The Sherman Act forbids any attempt to monopolize. The distinction between real monopolization and attempted monopolization is that in the former, the general purpose of acting is necessary, but in the latter, the intent, which may be proven by proof of unfair methods on the side of the competitor, is required. To establish a conspiracy to monopolize, three basic things are to be proved: (Radhu & Tare, 2019)

a. proof of conspiracy

b. specific intention to monopolize

c. An overt act in furtherance of the conspiracy, and there is no need to establish the market power.


Price Fixing

The Competition Act includes the word price association, i.e., price-fixing; however, it does not elaborate on vertical and horizontal price-fixing. Vertical price-fixing occurs when a manufacturer uses its dominating position to fix the price with a retailer; horizontal price-fixing occurs when a manufacturer sets the price with another manufacturer. Vertical pricing is also known as price maintenance, and an agreement between a film distributor and an operator, for example, is prohibited. Price maintenance agreements do not allow a patentee to regulate its resale price. Prices are generally established when they are agreed upon.

Section 132 of the Sherman Act additionally indicates that while the broadcast or exchange of price information does not in and of itself constitute a violation of Section 1, pricing information and the criminal intent to fix prices do. However, a combination or conspiracy under section 1 where rivals agree to share information on the pricing of the application.


Tying Agreement

Binding agreements are defined by the Sherman Act as an agreement entered into by a party to sell a product, but only if the customer either buys another product or agrees not to buy that product from another supplier. Tying arrangements are not unlawful in and of themselves. An unlawful tying arrangement occurs when a vendor demands a consumer to purchase another, less desirable, or cheaper product in addition to the desired one to reduce competition in the linked product. The Sherman Act further underlined the need to separate related items since there is no unlawful tying agreement if the products are comparable and the market is identical.


Amalgamation

According to the Sherman Act, an amalgamation is illegal in two ways: first, it removes considerable competition, and second, it creates a monopoly. There are two kinds of amalgamation: horizontal and vertical. For example, if two businesses are significant competitive players in a relevant market, a merger or consolidation between them violates the Sherman Act if it eliminates competition. If a corporation loses money and wishes to dissolve, the horizontal merger is not prohibited. Vertical amalgamation is only unlawful if the illegality is activated:

a) The purpose or intent with which it was conceived

b) The power it creates in the relevant market.


Clayton Act

After the Sherman Act supplementing the Sherman Act, another law was proclaimed in 1914 named Federal Antitrust Laws: Clayton Act.

Mergers

Vertical and horizontal fusions were specified under this statute. A vertical merger occurs when a buyer and seller unite, whereas a horizontal merger occurs when direct competitors merge. A conglomerate merger is neither vertical nor horizontal. The 33rd Competition Act makes no mention of conglomerate mergers. As defined under the Clayton Act, a pure conglomerate merger is an unconnected combination between the buyer and the acquired firm.


Indian Competition Law Perspective on Abuse of Dominance

“Section 4(2) of the (Indian) Competition Act 2002 (the Act) provides that there shall be an abuse of a dominant position if an enterprise or a group: directly or indirectly imposes unfair or discriminatory conditions or prices in the purchase or sale of goods or services; restricts or limits production of goods or services in the market; restricts or limits technical or scientific development relating to goods or services to the prejudice of consumers; indulges in practices resulting in a denial of market access; makes the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by other parties of supplementary obligations, which, by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts; or uses its dominance in one market to enter into or protect its position in other relevant markets (i.e., leveraging).” (Paris, 2017)

There can be no abuse in the absence of dominance, so, as a first step, the dominance of an organization in a relevant market must be created. In Uber India Systems Private Limited v CCI (2019), the Supreme Court held that the losses made by Uber per trip were prima facie indicative of abuse (through predatory pricing) as well as of dominance itself.


Exploitative and Exclusionary Practices

Section 4 is written broadly enough to include exploitative and discriminatory acts, but this is not explicitly stated. The CCI remarked in HT Media Ltd v Super Cassettes Ltd (2014) (HT Media case) that pricing abuses might be 'exclusionary' (i.e., pricing techniques employed by dominant corporations to exclude competitors) or 'exploitative' (i.e., which cover instances where a dominant firm is accused of exploiting its customers by setting excessive prices). In this instance, the CCI found Super Cassettes Industries Limited's minimum commitment charges (MCC) to be both exploitative and discriminatory. (Chawla, 2015)

The CCI has considered exploitative practices such as exorbitant pricing and unjust contract conditions in a number of cases. The CCI reviewed the passenger car market and the aftermarkets, including spare parts, diagnostic tools, and the supply of after-sales repair and maintenance services, in Shri Shamsher Kataria v Honda Siel Cars India Ltd & Ors (2014) (Auto Parts case). It discovered that 14 automobile manufacturers misused their dominating positions in their respective aftermarkets by requiring customers to buy replacement parts and diagnostic kits only from the carmaker or its authorized dealers. Using the necessary facilities concept, the CCI determined that this amounted to a limitation of market access to rivals. The CCI also found that the car manufacturers had engaged in excessive pricing of their spare parts (Singhal, 2017).


The link between dominance and abuse

The CCI is not necessary to show a nexus between abusive behavior and a dominating position. Any given behavior looks to be abusive if undertaken by a powerful organization.

It is also unnecessary for dominance to exist in the same market where anticompetitive behavior is felt. According to Section 4(2)(e) of the Act, abuse of a dominant position occurs when a dominant organization utilizes its dominating position in one relevant market to enter or defend a dominant position in another relevant market.


Specific Forms of Abuse


Types of Conduct

Rebate Schemes

The Indian Competition Act 2002 makes no mention of discounts or rebate programs. However, rebate schemes may be considered unfair or discriminatory prices and conditions, or other exclusionary practices (e.g., practices that limit or control the production of goods and the supply of services, or practices that result in the denial of market access), and thus may be covered by the Act (Sandhu, Arora, & Chopra, 2021).

The Competition Commission of India determined in the Intel case (2014) that Intel's incentive and target schemes did not preclude rivals and that this was reflected in the distribution of competing microprocessors by Intel's distributors and OEMs. The complainant's claim that distributors were barred from dealing in competitive items was judged to be unfounded. Furthermore, the CCI determined Intel's incentive programs to be legitimate business practices because they aimed to promote sales of low-demand items and gave non-predatory discounts to compete (Bisen, 2019).


Tying and Bundling

Unilateral tying and leveraging are considered abusive under section 4(2)(d) and section 4(2)(e) of the act.

The CCI set out the conditions for prohibited tie-in arrangements under section 3(4) of the act (which deals with anti-competitive vertical agreements but has some bearing on tying under section 4) in Sonam Sharma v Apple (2013): the presence of two separate products or services capable of being tied. The purchase of one commodity must be contingent on the purchase of another; the seller must have sufficient economic power over the tying product to appreciably restrain free competition in the market for the tied product; and the tying arrangement must affect a 'not insignificant amount of commerce: a tie-in arrangement is only considered abusive if it affects a 'substantial' portion of the market (Kamdar, 2013).


Exclusive Dealing

Exclusive dealing, non-compete agreements, and single branding limitations might all be characterized as practices that result in the denial of market access, as covered by section 4(2)(c), or limiting production or technological advancement, as covered by section 4(2). (b). As a requirement under Section 4 of the Act, the CCI is progressively analyzing the foreclosure effect of such activity (Radhu & Tare, 2019).


Predatory pricing

Explanation (b) to Section 4 of the Act establishes a two-step process for determining whether the behavior of a dominating organization is predatory. First, the price must be below cost (as measured by CCI standards), and second, the dominant firm must want to decrease or eliminate competitors.

The CCI has released standards for establishing production costs, which say that the average variable cost is the default cost benchmark (as a proxy for marginal cost). However, depending on the nature of the industry, market, and technology utilized, the CCI and the Director General (DG) may consider alternative cost criteria such as avoidable cost, long-run average incremental cost, and market value, with written justification (Sandhu, Arora, & Chopra, 2021).


Price or Margin Squeezes

Price squeezes, although not explicitly referred to in the act, would be covered where they amount to unfair or discriminatory pricing terms under section 4(2)(a)(ii) of the act and denial of market access under section 4(2)(c) of the act.

In the case of In Re: XYZ v Association of Man-Made Fibre Industry of India (2020) (GIL case), the CCI issued its single infringement order of the year, finding Grasim Industries (GIL) to have abused its dominant position in the market for the supply of viscose staple fiber (VSF) to spinners in India. While not a margin squeeze assessment, the CCI found that GIL had misused its dominant position by employing a discriminatory pricing strategy in which it charged more excellent rates to its downstream and domestic customers than to its international clients. Refusals to deal and denied access to essential facilities (Sandhu, Arora, & Chopra, 2021).

Access to essential facilities would be covered under practices resulting in a denial of market access under section 4(2)(c) and possibly section 4(2)(b), which prohibits limitations or restrictions on the production of goods or provision of services or technical or scientific development relating to goods or services to the prejudice of consumers.


Predatory Product Design or A Failure to Disclose New Technology

Although the act does not limit reasonable requirements for the protection of intellectual property rights (IPRs) in anticompetitive agreements, there is no specific reference to IPRs in the act's abuse of dominant position provisions. An unreasonable unilateral refusal to license an IPR or a discriminatory price between two enterprises can be considered an abuse of dominant position if these actions result in the imposition of an unfair condition or price, denial of market access, limiting production, technical or scientific development, or price discrimination, or any combination of these (Radhu & Tare, 2019).

In the Auto Parts case (2014), the CCI held that an unreasonable denial of market access by a dominant company could not be defended based on holding IP rights and would be considered abusive under section 4 (Sandhu, Arora, & Chopra, 2021).

 

Price Discrimination

Section 4(2)(a)(i) of the act prohibits non-price discrimination, and section 4(2)(a)(ii) prohibits price discrimination.

In the Schott Glass appeal (2014), the COMPAT determined that price discrimination abuse required the fulfillment of two ingredients: (1) unequal treatment of analogous transactions; and (2) injury/likely harm to competition by which purchasers were disadvantaged against each other. The COMPAT offered more advice on discriminatory behavior by stating that "the price and conditions could be said to be discriminatory if, and only if, they were different for the same quantities of the same product. (Sandhu, Arora, & Chopra, 2021)" The CCI has followed the COMPAT's approach to discriminatory conduct in the Intel case, where the CCI observed that: it appears to be a common business practice to give a better discount to the bulk purchase and unless it impedes the ability of the reseller to compete any competition may not probably arise . . . the alleged pricing policy of Intel does not amount to secondary line price discrimination and has not resulted in the foreclosure of any of its downstream customers (Kamdar, 2013).


Exploitative Prices or Terms of Supply

The CCI has considered exploitative practices such as exorbitant pricing and unjust contract conditions in a number of cases. The CCI determined that 14 automobile firms exploited their dominating positions in the Auto Parts case (2014) by forcing customers to acquire replacement parts and diagnostic instruments only from the relevant car maker or their authorized dealers. While deciding the appeal, the COMPAT agreed with the CCI's conclusion that the margins from the spare business significantly outweighed the margins from the vehicle-selling business and ruled that the automobile firms were charging an unfair price in the spare-parts market. The Supreme Court has suspended the COMPAT's verdict on appeal (Budholia, Gopalakrishnan, & Rajain, 2019).

On the contrary, the COMPAT's ruling in the Orissa Steel Federation case (2016) follows the approach of EU courts regarding excessive pricing: the CCI must establish unfairness in addition to arguing that a price is excessive. Aside from expenses, the CCI should take into account the gap between what the dominant business and other firms may charge, what various consumers pay, if customers can still be profitable, and whether there is a supply shortage (in which case high prices may be an efficient method of allocating the product) (Sandhu, Arora, & Chopra, 2021).

In the HT Media case, which is now under appeal before the NCLAT, the CCI considered the minimum commitment charges imposed by SCIL as exploitative (Laghate, 2013).


Abuse of Administrative or Government Process

Section 4 of the Act may cover abuses in the nature of sham litigation that result in denial of market access and limiting production, technical or scientific development.

Bulls Machines filed a complaint with the CCI in the matter of Bulls Machines v JCB India Ltd (JCB) (2014), alleging that JCB abused the legal process to remove rivals. The complaint was filed as a result of JCB's proceedings before the High Court of Delhi alleging infringement of JCB's design registrations and copyright by Bulls Machines in developing the backhoe loader 'Bull Smart'; JCB obtained an ex-parte injunction against Bulls Machines on the basis of alleged design infringements. The Delhi High Court eventually suspended the interim ruling. The CCI found there was a prima facie case that JCB had abused its dominant position in the manufacture and sale of backhoe loaders in India by initiating these proceedings and directed the DG to proceed with the investigation (Lath, 2014).


Mergers and Acquisitions as Exclusionary Practices

Although structural abuses are not directly addressed in the act's abuse of dominance provisions, the act's merger control requirements necessitate obligatory pre-notification of combinations that exceed specified financial criteria set out in section 5 of the act. Combinations that have or are expected to have a significant negative impact on competition in India are invalid (Paris, 2017).

Mergers and acquisitions that do not satisfy these financial requirements may be evaluated under Section 3 of the Act for engaging in anticompetitive agreements or Section 4 of the Act for abuse of dominance; however, no transaction has been reviewed under these provisions to date. Section 4(2)(c) of the act may be wide enough to capture any form of denial of market access, including through mergers and acquisitions if they are exclusionary (Sandhu, Arora, & Chopra, 2021).

 

The Microsoft Case

Microsoft, the world's largest software company, has been the subject of multiple antitrust proceedings in both the United States and the European Union. Microsoft has been accused of squeezing vendors and customers. Microsoft's strategies included aggressive pricing, bundling, and discriminatory deals. The diverse nature of the Microsoft abuse of dominance case exposes features of antitrust trust regulations on dominant businesses as well as the disparities in methods taken by US and EU antitrust regulators.


The United States versus Microsoft

In 1993, the US Department of Justice investigated Microsoft for exploiting its monopoly in operating systems. Microsoft used exclusive licensing strategies. It offered significant price cuts to personal computer makers in exchange for agreeing to pay for the installation of the Windows operating system on all PCs they sold. Manufacturers were thus penalized if they did not install Windows. Microsoft was also accused of tightly coupling its apps with its operating system (Economides, 2001).

The inquiry ended in an antitrust settlement between Microsoft and the Department of Justice that was accepted by an appeal court in 1995, in which Microsoft agreed not to enter into similar violating rebates and tying arrangements in the future (Sherman, 2008, 327). However, Microsoft was later accused by Netscape of tying its browser to its operating system, therefore breaking the 1995 agreement. Microsoft contended that the internet search engine Explorer, which debuted in 1995, was not a product but rather a function and so did not breach the settlement. This term was not accepted by the Department of Justice (DoJ). However, an appeals court ruled against the tying injunction in 1998. The bundling was deemed legal by the Court since it was convenient for customers and reduced expenses. Microsoft was again indicted under the US antitrust laws for infringing section 2 of the Sherman Act by the US Department of Justice and nineteen US states in 1998. Microsoft was accused of being engaged in a pattern or practice of illegal behavior. Under such a charge, the defendant can be declared guilty whether or not every one of its challenged acts was a violation (Sherman, 2008, 328) (Brouwer, 2011). The claims included monopolistic power abuse in connecting its operating system and web browser together, as well as other unlawful behavior. It was also accused of impeding Sun's emergence as a competitor operating system. It duped independent Java software developers who created Java programs for Windows by rendering them incompatible with environments other than Windows. Microsoft was accused of engaging in exclusive and binding relationships with computer manufacturers once more. Manufacturers received a significant discount for including Windows (including Explorer) on their machines. Furthermore, Microsoft threatened to terminate OEM licensing if manufacturers did not remove the Explorer icon from their desktops. With the exception of Java, the claims were, therefore, virtually identical to the previous antitrust action. The judge agreed that Microsoft had broken antitrust rules by utilizing exclusionary techniques to monopolize the operating system industry. It was accused of tying and predation since it distributed its browsers for free. The Court held that Microsoft had effectively shut out competitors by tying its browser to its operating system. As a result of this action, Netscape was forced out of the browser business. Microsoft said that such bundling improved the product's efficacy. However, these arguments were determined to be unjustified because tying did not increase Microsoft Windows speed. Microsoft had also signed agreements with online content producers. When viewed using Netscape Navigator rather than Internet Explorer, these contracts damaged the content of these providers.

The Court also declared Microsoft's Java tactics to be in breach of Section 2 of the Sherman Act. As a structural remedy, the US Court judgment in the Microsoft case in 2000 entailed the division of Microsoft into an operating system unit and a unit that developed other software components. As a remedy, the suing states also requested that Microsoft release the source code for its Internet Explorer web browser. As a behavior remedy, the judge ruled that Microsoft should provide rival software developers with the same application program interface information as Microsoft software developers and charge uniform license prices to all OEMs. Microsoft had to provide unbundled copies of new product features as well. Microsoft contested the ruling, and the appeals court ruled that Microsoft did not need to be split into two companies. The behavior remedies, however, were upheld (Sherman, 2008). The Appeals Court upheld the original case's factual findings. Before going to the Supreme Court, Microsoft reached a consent agreement with the DOJ in 2001. The agreement forbade Microsoft from using agreements or threats to restrict computer makers or software developers from doing business with Microsoft's competitors. They were also forbidden from customizing their operating systems in such a way that they interfered with other applications, such as Java. Microsoft was also compelled to reveal the interface codes or server protocols required to create competing software that would operate on its operating system. In 2002, the judge issued a Final Judgment. Microsoft was required to provide its application programming interfaces with third-party organizations and to create a three-person panel to oversee compliance with the settlement. The settlement, however, did not address the critical issue of tying/bundling Explorer into Windows (Economides, 2001).


The EU Microsoft Case

Following suit, the European Commission initiated its own action against Microsoft. The commission looked examined the inclusion of Windows Media Player in Windows. After a five-year inquiry, the commission concluded in 2004 that Microsoft had exploited its dominant position by improperly attaching its Media Player to the Windows operating system. It had also exploited its supremacy by refusing to give Sun Microsystems inside the structure required by a workgroup server to interface with Windows-powered personal PCs. By withholding interoperability information from server provider Sun, Microsoft erected a barrier to entry, resulting in a purposeful exclusionary refusal to deal that constrained technological advancement to the cost of the consumer. Microsoft said that their failure to provide interoperability information was necessary to defend its intellectual property rights, which had cost the company billions of dollars in R&D spending. According to the Commission, the primary role of intellectual property rights is to foster creativity for the broad public welfare. A refusal to award a license may thus be detrimental to the public welfare. The commission mandated that Microsoft provide a version of Windows without the Media Player. In addition, the commission ordered Microsoft to make interoperability information available at a reasonable fee and without discrimination (Brouwer, 2011).

Microsoft got a 497-million-euro penalty for violating EU competition legislation. Microsoft filed an appeal with the EU Court of First Instance against the 2004 Commission finding and order, requesting that the execution of the decision be postponed until the appeal procedure was completed. However, the European Court granted the requested stay while awaiting an appeal in December 2004. Microsoft paid the punishment and released versions of Windows that did not include the Media Player. Many of its protocols were also licensed to developers within the EU and the European Economic Area. However, Microsoft was fined 280 million euros in 2006 for failing to comply with EU directives.

Microsoft dropped its legal action in November 2007, when the Court of First Instance in Luxemburg upheld the commission's judgment. In February 2008, the European Commission penalized Microsoft an extra 899 million euros for failing to comply with the 2004 verdict. The European Commission predicated its penalty for noncompliance on Microsoft's allegedly excessive royalties and fees imposed to license purchasers. The commission judged Microsoft's royalty charges to be exorbitant. Microsoft software was deemed an important service that should be offered at no cost. Royalties on Microsoft global licenses were decreased from 5.95 percent to 0.4% of the licensee's earnings. The cost of interoperability information has been decreased to a one-time fixed price of 10000 euros. This, however, did not satisfy the commission. Microsoft argued that it was left in the dark about the interpretation of the commission's order, making compliance difficult. Until that point, the Microsoft fines were the biggest ever imposed on a firm by EU competition authorities.

In contrast to regulation, competition policy does not determine pricing. When it comes to acceptable conditions of access, the necessary facilities theory blurs this difference. This might prompt an antitrust regulator to issue a ruling on which pricing is acceptable and which is not. As a result, the European Commission gave an opinion on the fees Microsoft might charge for access to its source code (Stratemans, 2008).


The Google Search Case

EU Case

The commission has also investigated and sanctioned Google's abuses of dominant position with fines amounting to €1.49 billion in another case concerning Google search advertisements that appear on other websites. Google exploited its market dominance by enforcing various restrictive conditions in contracts with third-party websites, preventing Google's competitors from putting search advertisements on these websites. The wrongdoing continued for ten years, denying other firms the opportunity to compete on merit and innovate, as well as customers the advantages of competition. Google's competitors were unable to compete on merit, either because there was an express restriction for them to appear on publisher websites or because Google reserved by far the most valuable commercial space on those websites while limiting how rival search advertisements may show (Author, 2021).


India Case

The informants, namely Matrimony.com Limited and Consumer Unity and Trust Society, raised many allegations vis-à-vis abuse of dominance (AoD) by Google. However, this post shall focus on the three main allegations where Google was held liable for AoD, namely:

·       Display of ‘universal results’[2] in fixed positions in the search engine results page (SERP), in deviation from the order of relevance;

·       Manipulation of the search algorithm to favor its own search vertical services like Google flight, Google maps, etc., which are prominently displayed in the SERP; and

·       Imposing of unfair conditions in the syndication/intermediation agreements with website publishers.

The Competition Commission of India (CCI) fined Google INR 135.86 crores (approximately $1.36 billion) in its decision issued on February 8, 2018, for abusing its dominant position by engaging in search bias vis-à-vis Google flights service and imposing unfair terms in intermediation agreements with website owners incorporating Google's search bar and/or ad. The current ruling establishes the tone for CCI's engagement in India's digital economy, which would need a delicate balance of antitrust action and market innovation (Muralidharan, 2018).


Rationale of the European Commission

The EU Commission held Google dominant on the basis of the following grounds. (i) Market Share, (ii) existing barriers to entry and expansion7, (iii) the infrequency of user multi-homing and the existence of brand effects, and (iv) the lack of countervailing buyer power (Author, 2021).

In prior dominant judgments, the European Commission distinguished between the market for general internet search and vertical internet search, which is a specialized online search on certain categories such as travel, legal, and medical. According to the fact sheet, the European Commission concluded that Google is a dominant player in all EEA countries' national markets, with market shares of more than 90% for general internet search since 2008, with the exception of the Czech Republic, where the commission found Google to be dominant since 2011 (Brouwer, 2011). A large amount of time and resources, such as research and development, are necessary to design an effective search engine. Furthermore, to give relevant results for searches, the search engine should get a significant volume of traffic, allowing it to enhance the user experience and detect any changes in user behavior. Furthermore, the positive feedback effect resulting from direct and indirect network effects acts as an additional barrier to entrance. The behavior of users in the EEA demonstrates that only a minority of users transfer to other general search services after using Google general search as their primary general search service, a phenomenon known as multi-homing (Author, 2021). Talking about the lack of countervailing power, Google also agrees with the commission’s assertion that the users are not able to find any other services in relation to Google.


Rationale of the Competition Commission of India

As far as the dominance of Google in India is concerned, the investigation of the DG showcases that for a period of 6 (2009 to 2014) and 5 (2009 to 2013) years, Google was a dominant player in the market for general search services and online search advertising services respectively (Lamoreaux, 2019).

While considering Google's dominant position in India, the CCI reviewed not just its market share but also other considerations such as Google's size, economic strength, resources, entry hurdles, and commercial benefits. 87 According to DG, "strong entry obstacles exist in the form of high cost, technology, network effects, minimum scale requirements, and contractual constraints, among other things, that confer tremendous economic power on Google and position it at a significant advantage." 88 As a result of such substantial entry barriers, it may be stated that Google is able to play independently of competitive pressures in the relevant market (Author, 2021).

In order to maintain the confidentiality of the data submitted by Google with respect to market share for a specific period and traffic received by Google in both the markets, CCI has redacted the statistics and figures from the public version of the decision.


Conclusion

Competition law is a complicated combination of a country's legal, economic, and administrative policies aimed to promote economic competition. Because competition is thought to be necessary for economic development, competition law tries to safeguard economic competitiveness. The principle behind competition law is the excellent effect of competition on an economy's market, functioning as a safeguard against the abuse of economic power. The relationship between competition law and economic development has been stressed several times, and the necessity for a competition law appears to be on the agenda.

Over the last several years, the number of nations possessing competition legislation has risen, with few being substantially enforced. As economic activity increasingly crosses national boundaries, it is critical to ensure at least a fair degree of uniformity and convergence in the application of competition law to enterprises and behavior outside their borders.

Abuse of Dominance is subjective in a manner. The same provisions of the law can be explained differently. Now, most of the competition laws of abuse of dominance Rely on price or economic factors to determine competitive competitiveness. However, in the case of regulating big technology companies,  non-price factors need to be considered. One of the most essential non-price factors emerging nowadays is data. In addition to that, new provisions should be added to competition laws worldwide to tackle the issues with big techs. As these big techs operate worldwide, global harmonization of antitrust provisions would be necessary for coming years.

Although the fundamental concepts of competition law remain constant, the aims or outcomes cannot be the same across different countries. In essence, a progressive achievement of competition policy objectives would be the solution to an effective competition law regime in emerging nations. Although the application of competition legislation is not inherently undesirable, even at the outset of economic growth, its blind execution on the road traveled by industrialized countries can ruin its own goals. Thus, competition law is a complicated legislative invention that the Indian Government and the Competition Commission should take the time to comprehend and administer in light of the unique demands and requirements of the Indian economy.

 

References

Aditi. (2014). Abuse Of Dominance: The Microsoft Cases. Retrieved from lawoctopus: https://www.lawctopus.com/academike/abuse-of-dominance-the-microsoft-cases/

Author, U. (2021). Google: An Interminable Friction of Abuse of Dominance- A Comparative Study between the EU and India. IOSR Journal. Retrieved from https://www.iosrjournals.org/iosr-jhss/papers/Vol.26-Issue9/Ser-8/I2609085681.pdf

Bisen, A. (2019). Competition Commission of India orders probe against Intel for abuse of dominant position to protect parallel importers from its discriminatory warranty policy. Retrieved from Kluwer Competition Law Blog: http://competitionlawblog.kluwercompetitionlaw.com/2019/08/15/competition-commission-of-india-orders-probe-against-intel-for-abuse-of-dominant-position-to-protect-parallel-importers-from-its-discriminatory-warranty-policy/

Brouwer, M. (2011). US and EU Competition Policy on Abuse of Dominance in HighTech Industries. Retrieved from https://www.researchgate.net/publication/254914577_US_and_EU_competition_policy_on_abuse_of_dominance_in_high_tech_industries

Budholia, B., Gopalakrishnan, A., & Rajain, D. (2019). Landmark Decision by Delhi High Court on Constitutional Validity of Certain Provisions of the Competition Act. Retrieved from SCC Online Blog: https://www.scconline.com/blog/post/2019/06/06/landmark-decision-by-delhi-high-court-on-constitutional-validity-of-certain-provisions-of-the-competition-act/

Chawla, A. (2015). In Re: M/s HT Media Limited v. Super Cassettes Industries Limited. Retrieved from Lawctopus: https://www.lawctopus.com/academike/in-re-ms-ht-media-limited-v-super-cassettes-industries-limited/

Economides, N. (2001). The Microsoft Antitrust Case. Retrieved from neoeconomics: https://neconomides.stern.nyu.edu/networks/Microsoft_Antitrust.final.pdf

Kamdar, M. (2013). Vertical restraints: the positive effects. Retrieved from Law.asia: https://law.asia/sonam-sharma-v-apple-vertical-restraints/

Laghate, G. (2013). HT Media, Super Cassettes royalty row takes new turn. Retrieved from Business Standard: https://www.business-standard.com/article/current-affairs/ht-media-super-cassettes-royalty-row-takes-new-turn-113033100158_1.html

Lamoreaux, N. R. (2019). The Problem of Bigness: From Standard Oil to Google. Journal of Economic Perspectives.

Lath, A. (2014). Abuse of dominance: obtaining fraudulent ex parte interim injunctions for designs and copyrights. Retrieved from SpicyIP: https://spicyip.com/2014/03/abuse-of-dominance-obtaining-fraudulent-ex-parte-interim-injunctions-for-designs-and-copyrights.html

Makkar, K., & Jain, S. (2020). DATA-RELATED ABUSE OF DOMINANCE IN DIGITAL ECONOMY: A TEMPLATE FOR FUTURE REGULATION IN INDIA. Unpublished.

Muralidharan, S. (2018). India – Matrimony.com v. Google: A Cat on the Wall Approach to Intervening in the Expanding Digital Space. Retrieved from Kluwer Competition Law Blog: http://competitionlawblog.kluwercompetitionlaw.com/2018/03/20/india-matrimony-com-v-google-cat-wall-approach-intervening-expanding-digital-space/

Paris, A. (2017). Dominant position. Institute of Competition Law Concurrences.com.

Radhu, S., & Tare, P. (2019). Abuse of Dominance: A Comparative Study of India, U.S.A and United Kingdom”. www.penacclaims.com.

Sandhu, H. S., Arora, R., & Chopra, S. S. (2021). In brief: abuse of dominance in India. Retrieved from Lexology: https://www.lexology.com/library/detail.aspx?g=00e0f87a-ff41-4ba2-a6ff-5a026e7793b0

Singhal, A. (2017). Shamsher Kataria v. Honda Siel Cars India Ltd. – Great End, but Means? Retrieved from Kluwer Competition Law Blog: http://competitionlawblog.kluwercompetitionlaw.com/2017/05/09/shamsher-kataria-v-honda-siel-cars-india-ltd-great-end-but-means/

Stratemans, A. (2008). The EU Microsoft Case: Not a Soft Case .