Our life nowadays revolves
around many platforms. We interact with our acquaintances on social media platforms
like Facebook, shop different merchandise from Amazon/Flipkart, order food from
our favorite restaurants through Swiggy/Zomato, and book our hotels or flights
from MakeMyTrip/Oyo, taxis from Uber/Ola, and there are many such examples. One
of the unique characteristics of these platforms is that they are multi-sided,
e.g., all of these platforms have two or more distinct user groups.
A multisided-sided platform
(MSP) is one in which 1) two or more sets of agents interact through a mediator
or platform, and 2) each set of agents' actions impact the outcomes of the
other set of agents, generally through an externality
The advent of multi-sided
markets has eliminated or lowered transaction costs in conventional
marketplaces that they have tried to organize and frequently replace. On the
one hand, they have frequently assisted in overcoming market inefficiencies
without the need for govt interference, rendering many of the early grounds for
regulatory interventions obsolete and unviable
Most antitrust cases
concerning digital platform markets involve allegations of abuse of dominant
position. For Competition Authorities (C.A.s) to study any such cases,
determining the relevant market is crucial. Market definition of multi-sided
platforms is not the same as in the case of traditional one-sided businesses.
The initial question that arises is how many markets to define. As competition
analysis is empirical, the approach to market definition in cases of MSPs has
been different in different jurisdictions. This article wants to analyze the
approach of CCI in this regard.
The
Rationale for the topic as an entry point
With the growing popularity
of e-commerce, it is critical to resolving the issue of relevant market
definition, primarily between e-commerce platforms and traditional platforms.
The CCI must be well-equipped to carry out the findings of competition
breaches. The relevant product market must be carefully defined for the CCI to
adequately define and assess the borders within which the anti-competitive
behavior occurred. For that to happen, it is crucial to understand the
difficulties of assessing the definition of the relevant market in cases
involving MSPs and examine if the existing tools and criteria are enough to
regulate the anti-competitive behavior.
The
Research Questions
1. What are the distinct
characteristics that distinguish MSPs from general one-sided markets?
2. Are the existing tools for relevant
market determination enough for the MSPs?
3. What is a trend in CCI's
approach to relevant market definition in cases pertaining to MSPs?
To answer these questions,
I will conduct a brief literature review to understand the basic economics of
the MSPs and then analyze the CCI's approach to defining relevant markets in
some cases pertaining to MSPs in India.
Brief
Literature Survey
Despite their economic
relevance, multi-sided platform markets have only recently received attention
from economists in the scholarly literature on antitrust. The older literature
mainly focused on two-sided platform markets: traditional newspapers or payment
cards industry and operating system antitrust cases involving Microsoft in the
1990s. Viscusi
Figure 1- Network externalities in two-sided markets
Source: (Viscusi, Harrington, & Sappington, 2018)
In the OECD report
The market study by the CCI
Defining
Relevant Market
The relevant market is the
filter that defines the region of commerce within which competition authorities
examine a firm's behavior. Market determination aims to find items that put a
firm's products under competitive pressure and are interchangeable to the point
where the businesses producing them may be considered rivals.
According to Section 2(r)
of the Competition Act, 2002, “relevant market means the market which may be
determined by the Commission concerning the relevant product market or the
relevant geographic market or with reference to both the markets." The
first step in determining dominance is to define the relevant product and
geographic market. Sections 19(6) and 19(7) of the Act establish the parameters
for establishing the relevant geographic and product markets. The Competition
Act, 2002, like other competition laws across the world, focuses on
"substitutability" as a criterion for determining the relevant
market.
The "Small but
Significant, Non-Transitory Increase in Price" test, sometimes known as
the SSNIP test, is an essential technique for establishing substitutability.
SSNIP assesses whether consumers of a given product will switch to another
product in exchange for a minor but considerable price increase (roughly 5% to
10%). If this is the case, the two
items might be in the same market. This test is often referred to as the
"Hypothetical Monopolist Test" since it determines whether "a
relevant market is worth monopolizing"
A narrow market
determination that includes fewer substitute goods increases the likelihood
that a firm will be deemed dominant. Conversely, a broad market determination
may include many substitutes, leading Competition Authorities (C.A.) to
overlook instances of anti-competitive conduct.
This essay focuses on
determining appropriate product markets in scenarios involving MSPs. While
digital platform characteristics such as worldwide/national reach complicate
defining local markets, there appears to be some uniformity in how C.A.s,
notably the CCI, have tackled the matter
Difficulties
in determining Relevant Product Market
for Multi-sided Platforms
Multi-sided
marketplaces allow interactions between two or more user groups that produce
value for at least one of the user groups.
Network
effects can be of two types:
Conventional competition analysis has seen a platform's network size as a major component of its value and market power.
One
of the first instances involving two-sided markets in India was the MCX Vs. NSE
case, in which the CCI focused on the idea of network effects in its minority
order
Single market
vs. Multiple markets: Platform Typology Approach
Focusing
on platform nature or typology is recommended to facilitate the evaluation of
how many markets should be defined. The OECD recommends distinguishing between
transactional and non-transactional platforms
Payment
card systems, e-commerce marketplaces, and travel aggregators are examples of
transactional platforms where indirect network effects flow from both
sides.
Non-transactional
platforms, on the other hand, permit interactions between user groups that are
not transactions. As a result, they display solely unilateral cross-side
network effects. For example, increasing the number of users on a social media
site will almost certainly raise its worth to advertisers. However, growth in
the number of marketers does not necessarily harm the value gained by users.
Because
of bidirectional indirect network effects, both sides of transactional
platforms should be viewed as a single relevant market. Because distinct
economic considerations and alternatives may exist for the multiple sides in
non-transactional platforms, each side should represent a separate market
Substitutability Determination:
a transition from Quantitative to Qualitative Analysis
Applying
the SSNIP test to multi-sided marketplaces is complicated. The original SSNIP
test ignores the influence of indirect network effects on pricing mechanisms. A
price rise on one side of a multi-sided market might affect demand on the
other. A raise in the commission rate charged to drivers by a cab aggregator,
for example, may limit their motivation to give their services. Users would
migrate to platforms with a broader roster if there were fewer drivers. Fewer
consumers would reduce the number of drivers ready to provide their services on
the site even further. As a result, a hypothetical monopolist must account for
the impact of a big, non-transitory price rise on both sides of the market.
OECD suggests that to arrive at an accurate determination in multi-sided
marketplaces, the SSNIP test should be applied to both sides of the market
Adding more issues, some of the platforms offer services to one side of the user at zero cost, like Facebook, and charge from the other side of the user. So, applying the SSNIP test to the users of Facebook would be a failure because a 5-10% increase in prices will still make the price for the user a zero. So, the SSNIP test should be applied to both sides of the users.
The CCI’s Approach to Multi-sided Platform Markets
Single market vs. multimarket approach
The
CCI does not account for the interdependence between numerous user groups
generated by indirect network effects in most situations involving multi-sided
marketplaces. As a result, it has formed several unique and autonomous
marketplaces while ignoring linkages between the various sides supplied by
digital platforms. CCI often based its determination on which side had made the
complaint in question. In FHRAI vs. MakeMyTrip case, it said, “Since the
allegations in the present case are primarily concerning the hoteliers, the
relevant market analysis needs to be carried out from the perspective of
hoteliers”
However,
several of the CCI's recent rulings show a growing appreciation of multi-sided
marketplaces and the impact of network effects. The relevant market was
described in Lifestyle Equities CV Vs. Amazon as the "market for services
supplied by online platforms for selling items in India.
Assessment of Substitutability
The
CCI was tasked in Harshita Chawla v WhatsApp to examine whether the 'bundling'
of WhatsApp Pay, a UPI-enabled payments system, with WhatsApp amounted to an
abuse of power. The CCI designated the primary relevant market as the “market
for Over-The-Top (OTT) messaging applications using smartphones in India” to
gauge dominance. Also, noting in its analysis that communication apps may be
split into numerous distinct categories based on their unique features and
functions. It opted not to depend too heavily on the unique properties of
communication applications, instead of focusing on the “primary or most
dominant feature of the app to categorize it into a particular relevant market”
According
to the CCI, in the case of Ashish Ahuja v. Snapdeal and others, the buyer
prefers to examine discounts and shopping experience in both the online and
offline markets before making the ultimate choice to purchase the product. A
price rise in one sector may cause the consumer to migrate to another section.
As a result, CCI concluded that physical and online markets are not distinct
relevant markets since they differ primarily in their distribution channels
In
Meru vs. Uber case, the CCI separated radio taxis from other modes of
transportation such as rickshaws and other private taxis based on capabilities
such as time savings, predictability, and round-the-clock availability. Despite
these operational differences, it was determined that customers in Kolkata
significantly relied on yellow cabs for their everyday transportation needs,
and so the relevant market should comprise the services provided by radio taxis
and yellow cabs
A
similar approach was used to approve the merger of Facebook and Jaadhu Holdings
Pvt Ltd, with the CCI noting a gradual trend toward convergence in terms
of functionality between user apps, implying that relying on minor differences
in features may not be appropriate for relevant market determination
Conclusion
Initially,
the CCI's decisional practice did not wholly reflect the peculiarities of
multi-sided marketplaces, but more recent rulings consider the distinctive
aspects of digital platforms, such as indirect network effects. The CCI's
adoption of a more sophisticated approach to the relevant market determination
is unquestionably a step in the right direction. However, they need to be standardization in
defining relevant market in the cases involving MSPs in India; for that to
happen, the section 19(6) and 19(7) should not be an exclusive list, and CCI
had to have the independence in assessing different features and
functionalities and even consumer behavior when determining the relevant market
in cases involving MSPs.
References
Ashish Ahuja v.
Snapdeal and others, 17 of 2014 (CCI 2014). Retrieved from
https://www.cci.gov.in/sites/default/files/172014.pdf
Bhattacharjea, A.
(2018). Predatory Pricing in Platform Competition: Economic Theory and Indian
Cases. doi:10.1007/978-981-13-1232-8_11
CCI. (2020).
Market Study on E-commerce in India.
Chunduru, A.
(2020). Facebook Assures CCI Its Deal With Jio Involves Exchange Of Only
‘Limited Data’. Retrieved from medianama:
https://www.medianama.com/2020/10/223-cci-facebook-jaadhu-jio-platforms-limited-data/
Federation of
Hotel & Restaurant Associations of India (FHRAI) and Ors. v. MakeMyTrip
India Pvt. Ltd. and ors., 14 of 2019 (CCI 2019). Retrieved from
http://cci.gov.in/sites/default/files/Interim_Order_14-of-2019and01-of-2020.pdf
Hagiu, A., &
Wright, J. (2015). Multi-sided Platforms. Harvard Business School.
Retrieved from
https://www.hbs.edu/ris/Publication%20Files/15-037_cb5afe51-6150-4be9-ace2-39c6a8ace6d4.pdf
Harshita Chawla
v. Whatsapp and Facebook, 15 of 2020 (CCI 2020). Retrieved from
https://www.cci.gov.in/sites/default/files/15-of-2020.pdf
Koul, P. (.,
& Prasad, P. (2020). An Analysis of the Abuse of Dominant Position by the
E-Commerce Retailers in India. Amity.edu, 55-61.
Krishnan, A.,
& Unni, V. (2019). Competition Regulation in Two-Sided Markets: The
Indian Jurisprudence. National Conference on Economics of Competition Law ,
1-35.
Lifestyle
Equities C.V. and Ors. v. Amazon Sellers Service Private Limited & Anr.,
09 of 2020 (CCI 2020). Retrieved from
https://www.cci.gov.in/sites/default/files/09-of-2020.pdf
Mandrescu, D.
(2018). Applying (EU) competition law to online platforms: Reflections on the
definition of the relevant market(s). World Competition: Law and Economics
Review. Retrieved from
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3271624
MCX Stock
Exchange Ltd vs National Stock Exchange of India Ltd., 13/2009 (CCI 2009).
Meru Travel
Solutions Private Limited vs. Uber India Systems Private Limited and Ors, 96
of 2015 (Competition Commission of India 2015). Retrieved from
https://cuts-ccier.org/wp-content/uploads/2019/02/Edition-1-Meru-travel-solutions.pdf
OECD. (2018). Rethinking
Antitrust Tools for Multi-Sided Platforms. OECD.
Rysman, M.
(2009). The Economics of Two-Sided Markets. Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 125-143.
Sharma, K.
(2011). SSNIP Test: A Useful Tool, Not A Panacea. COMPETITION LAW REPORTS,
188-192.
Viscusi, W. K.,
Harrington, J. E., & Sappington, D. E. (2018). ECONOMICS OF REGULATION
AND ANTITRUST. Masachuttes: Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Table of
Figures
Figure 2 Direct Network Effect Source: Author
Figure 3 Indirect Network Effects Source: Author